Honours Research Paper
The Relevance and Propriety of Chasing Alpha:
A Study into Active versus Passive Investing in South Africa
Cameron L. Wilson
A research paper submitted to the School of Economics at the University of Cape Town in partial fulfilment of
the requirements for the Bachelor of Commerce Honours degree in Financial Analysis and Portfolio
Management.
Cape Town
2018
Approved by:
Lucian Pitt
© 2018
Cameron L. Wilson
ALL RIGHTS RESERVED
The Relevance and Propriety of Chasing Alpha:
A Study into Active versus Passive Investing in South Africa
(Under the supervision of Lucian Pitt)
Executive Summary
Although literature exploring the performance disparity between active and passive
investment strategies dates back decades, its relevance once again becomes apparent with the
rise of exchange traded funds (ETFs) in South Africa. The research question explores the
age-old question in a South African context and asks whether it is still appropriate and
relevant for active asset managers to chase excess returns at the risk of their clients’ capital.
The consulted literature largely tells the same story. It is evident that markets need to be
somewhat inefficient for active managers to capture excess returns. Proponents of efficient
capital markets hold the stance that active managers cannot generate excess returns
consistently. However, proponents of “mostly” efficient markets hold the stance that superior
managers with superior analysts and superb track records can generate excess returns
consistently. What is widely acknowledged is that the average active manager, after fees and
adjusted for risk, does not outperform their respective benchmark.
The consulted literature derives its conclusions from research conducted on large, deep, and
developed capital markets, primarily the United States’ capital market. A South African
context was chosen with the belief that its relatively small capital market may provide
opportunities for the average active manager to produce excess returns above the JSE Ltd All
Share Index (JSE ALSI).
The sample of active funds was drawn from the population of South African domiciled, Rand
denominated, active equity funds. Monthly returns data over a period of eight years was
considered as to include as many funds as possible whilst allowing enough time for returns
data to establish any trends that may be present. A second sample of ex-post “ superior” funds
was selected from the original sample. Both samples of active funds were tested against the
JSE ALSI, with respect to risk-adjusted return metrics, at the five percent level of
significance using the right-tailed Student’s T-test. All statistical tests were made given three
scenarios; zero fees, lower-bound fees, and higher-bound fees.
1
Before fees, the average active fund outperformed the passive JSE ALSI, as per consulted
literature. However, when fees were accounted for, the average active fund underperformed
the respective passive index. Again, this result fell in line with the consulted literature.
Interestingly, the average ex-post s uperior active fund outperformed the respective passive
fund when adjusted for risk and fees.
If superior actively managed funds can be selected using historic risk-analyses and historic
performance-metrics of funds and fund-managers, then alpha should be generated on a
recurring basis. However, the capturing of recurring alpha returns relies on an active
management of funds, that is, actively managing one’s portfolio of active funds, ignoring
transaction costs and taxes. Given the apparent failure of the average actively managed fund
compared to the JSE ALSI benchmark, it is not advisable to hold a passive instrument which
tracks active funds, such as a fund tracker ETF or index-styled investment vehicles tracking
active funds.
Key Words: Active vs Passive, Index Investing, Excess Returns, South Africa, JSE Ltd.
2
Acknowledgements
My sincerest gratitude, first and foremost, goes to my supervisor, Lucian Pitt. Lucian has
been actively involved in my academic career, providing invaluable insight, from my
undergraduate years to my final postgraduate days at the University of Cape Town (UCT).
His sincerity and passion for his students is truly remarkable, making him an invaluable asset
to UCT’s academic body.
Secondly, my parents’ unwavering emotional and financial support has made this journey
possible. Without their backing, I would not have had the opportunity to study at this fine
institution. I am unbelievably fortunate to have been granted the opportunities they have
made possible.
Finally, without the University of Cape Town’s resources, the research could not have been
conducted. Gratitude goes to the individuals that make UCT the world-class institution it is
today.
3
Table of Contents
Executive Summary
i
Acknowledgements
iii
Table of Contents
iv
Table of Figures
v
List of Abbreviations
vi
Literature Review
1
Introduction
1
Efficient Markets and the Foundation of Passive Management
1
The Defence of Efficient Markets and the CAPM
2
‘Mostly Efficient’ Markets and The Defence of Active Management
4
Is Active and Passive Management Mutually Exclusive?
5
Literature Evaluation and Working Hypothesis in a South African Context
6
Conclusion
6
Methodology
7
Introduction
7
Paradigm
7
Theoretical Framework
8
Research Approach/Research Design
9
Data Collection
10
Validity and Reliability
11
Data Analysis Strategy
11
Ethical Considerations
12
Conclusion
12
Results and Discussion
13
Introduction
13
Descriptive Statistics
13
Risk-Adjusted Performance before Fees
14
Risk-Adjusted Performance after Fees
16
Implications of Findings
18
Concluding Remarks
19
Limitations and Recommendations
19
References
vii
4
Table of Figures
Table 1: Mean monthly measures of central tendency
13
Table 2: Mean monthly risk-adjusted metrics before fees.
14
Table 3: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, zero fees. Average active
fund vs J203.
15
Table 4: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, zero fees. Average
superior (ex-post) active fund vs J203.
16
Table 5: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, lower-bound Fees.
Average active fund vs J203
16
Table 6: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, lower-bound fees.
Average superior (ex-post) active fund vs J203
17
Table 7: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, higher-bound fees.
Average active fund vs J203.
18
Table 8: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, higher-bound fees.
Average superior (ex-post) active fund vs J203.
5
18
List of Abbreviations
CAPM
Capital Asset Pricing Model
ETF
Exchange Traded Fund
EMH
Efficient Market Hypothesis
HML
High Minus Low
JSE ALSI
JSE Ltd All Share Index
M2
Modigliani-Modigliani
MPT
Modern Portfolio Theory
MRP
Market Risk Premium
RAP
Risk-Adjusted Performance
SD
Standard Deviation
SMB
Small Minus Big
SSD
Semi Standard Deviation
UCT
University of Cape Town
6
Literature Review
Introduction
Literature on active and passive investment strategies date back to the early fifties when
Harry Markowitz introduced Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) in his 1952 article, Portfolio
Selection, which featured in The Journal of Finance. It was not until the introduction of the
Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH), by Eugene Fama and Paul Samuelson in 1965, did the
debate between active and passive management truly capture the attention of finance and
economics audiences alike (Delcey, 2018). This literature review explores active and passive
management through various concepts underlying both investment strategies. First, the
theoretical foundations of active and passive investing strategies are laid down through the
exploration of the EMH. The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) and pricing anomalies are
discussed. The case for active management is considered with reference to; “mostly efficient
markets”, the value added of active management, and acute market inefficiencies. Finally,
allocation between, and the optimisation of, active and passive investment strategies will be
evaluated.
Efficient Markets and the Foundation of Passive Management
A perfectly efficient market is one in which new publicly-available information is
disseminated in a timely and costless manner to all market participants and is one in which
trade-execution costs are zero (Vasicek & McQuown, 1972). The EMH does not hold up
perfectly as theory suggests, but empirical evidence shows that the main conclusions of
EMH, namely the weak-form and semi-strong form efficiency, hold up very well in real
markets (Vasicek & McQuown, 1972). The EMH is said to follow three forms of efficiency:
1) weak-form efficiency: where historic information is priced into current stock prices, 2)
semi-strong-form efficiency: where historic and current information is priced into current
stock prices, and 3) strong-form efficiency: where historic, current, and insider information1
is priced into current stock prices (Fama, 1969).
1
In strong-form market efficiency it is assumed that non-public, material information pertaining to company
management and idiosyncratic factors is disseminated to all market participants timeously and at zero cost.
1
Given Markowitz’ and Fama’s contribution of MPT and the EMH respectively, Treynor
(1962), Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966) independently developed the
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). The CAPM describes the determination of asset
prices, given a market in equilibrium, by considering an asset’s systematic risk relative to the
market portfolio’s2 risk (Eun, 1994). Together, MPT, the EMH, and the CAPM form the
foundation upon which active versus passive investment strategies are debated.
The logic of passive investing or “beta grazing” considers the fees to advisors, brokerage
fees, bid-ask spreads, and marginal risks undertaken from chasing an active investment
strategy for no guarantee of matching or outperforming the market portfolio (Keane, 1986)
(Liebowitz, 2005). This logic is founded upon the assumption that markets are perfectly
efficient and that CAPM holds, implied by perfectly efficient markets. Whereas active
management relies on the assumption that assets can be mispriced through market
inefficiencies.
The Defence of Efficient Markets and the CAPM
Since the inception of the CAPM many market-related pricing anomalies have been
discovered with academics disputing the CAPM, thus, the legitimacy of the model has been
undermined (Eun, 1994). The most well-known critique of the CAPM is from Roll (1976) in
what is known today as ‘Roll’s Critique’ in finance classrooms. The CAPM is a single-factor
model which only considers the “beta risk”3 or systematic risk of an asset with respect to the
systematic risk of the Market Portfolio to determine the price of said asset. Roll critiques the
CAPM as only useful for testing the mean-variance efficiency of the Market Portfolio (Roll,
1976). That is, if the Market Portfolio is the optimal, mean-variance portfolio as per
Markowitz’s MPT, then will assets only be correctly priced by the model (Roll, 1976). Roll
says, “There is an ‘if and only if’ relation between return/beta linearity and market portfolio
mean-variance efficiency” (1976: p.130).
The fundamental flaw of the CAPM lies in the fact that it relies on an ‘unobservable market
portfolio’ (Eun, 1994). Eun proposes that the CAPM has been incorrectly specified, saying
that there is a part of the market portfolio that is certainly observable, be it a broad market
2
The market portfolio is a collection of every tradable asset weighted by its prominence in the asset universe
and is assumed to be held by all rational, risk averse investors (Markowitz, 1952).
3
Beta risk is the measure of how sensitive an asset’s returns are relative to the Market Portfolio’s returns. It is
the covariance of the asset’s returns and the Market Portfolio’s returns divided by the variance of the Market
Portfolio’s returns (Sharpe, 1964). Where β=COV(Ri,Rm)VAR(Rm). Alternatively, is the slope coefficient
when the single asset returns are regressed on the Market Portfolio’s returns.
2
index or a portfolio tracking a large array of assets4, and a part of the market portfolio that is
unobservable (Eun, 1994). Eun deconstructed the CAPM’s β into the observable β and the
unobservable or ‘latent β ’, reformulating the CAPM5, which he then used to tackle asset
pricing anomalies (1994). Using this definition of the CAPM, Eun was able to solve the more
prominent anomalies brought forward by Friend and Blume (1970), Banz (1981), and
Reinganum (1981).
Friend and Blume found that positive Jensen’s Alpha6 returns are inversely related to an
asset’s beta coefficient (Friend & Blume, 1970). Eun found that the Friend/Blume anomaly is
perfectly consistent with the CAPM so long as the benchmark and latent portfolios are
positively correlated to each other (Eun, 1994).
Banz (1981) and Reinganum (1981) found that asset returns are inversely correlated to firm
size in what is known as the ‘firm size effect’ or ‘small firm effect’. Smaller firms
experienced higher returns even after adjusting for beta-specific risk (Banz, 1981)
(Reinganum, 1981). Eun proposes that this market anomaly is explained by the relative sizes
of the latent betas: that the small firm effect is consistent with the CAPM so long as the latent
beta of the smaller firm is larger than the latent beta of the larger firm (1994).
Eun has effectively solved some of the more prominent anomalies associated with the CAPM
through his theoretical and mathematical approach to decomposing beta-risk. However, the
practical value of this theory is limited as pricing unobservable components of risk becomes
highly problematic.
4
This portfolio can be set up as a theoretical benchmark for academic purposes or developed for investment
purposes. However, the cost of purchasing and rebalancing such a portfolio through full replication would offset
any benefit gained through diversification. This implied cost relates to the costs of ‘over-diversification’ (Denis,
Denis & Yost, 2002:-).
5
Treynor (1962), Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin’s (1966) single factor CAPM estimates asset prices
based on the risk-free rate and a proportion of the market-risk premium determined by the coefficient.
Ri=Rf+i,m(Rm-Ri). Reformulated, Eun suggests a CAPM which accounts for the unobserved . Thus:
Ri=Rf+Bi,B+Li,L where Bi,B is the observable benchmark beta and Li,L is the unobservable latent beta (Eun,
1994).
6
Jensen’s Alpha is a risk-adjusted measure for returns above or below the security market line found in the
CAPM and can thus be positive or negative.
3
‘Mostly Efficient’ Markets and The Defence of Active Management
Active investment strategies involve strategic asset allocation and risk expenditure in
accordance with prescribed investment mandates to match or beat a benchmark. “The
objective of active management is to maximise the value added from residual return, where
the objective awards a credit for the expected residual return and a debit for the residual risk”
(Grinold & Kahn, 2000, p. 119).
It is reasonable to assume that developed markets satisfy weak-form and semi-strong-form
market efficiency: that current asset prices on developed exchanges reflect all historic and
current data (Fama, 1970). By this argument, it is also reasonable to assume that there is no
place for active management and that all rational investors will hold a passive portfolio that
ticks along with the market. Contrary to the EMH, Grossman and Stiglitz argue that in a
world of costly information, analysts must receive a premium for their work or else there
would be no incentive for these analysts to collect and analyse data (1980). It is by this
process of data analysis that markets are operationally efficient which results in efficient
price discovery by market participants. Put simply, Jones and Wermers remark, “markets
need to be ‘mostly but not completely efficient’ or else investors would not make the effort to
assess whether prices are ‘fair’” (2011:31). It is thus reasonable to conclude that markets are
weak-form and semi-strong-form efficient due to the market participation of active managers
whom assure that price discovery is an efficient process.
“By making markets more efficient, active management improves capital allocation –
and thus economic efficiency and growth – resulting in greater aggregate wealth for society
as a whole.” (Jones & Wermers, 2000:31).
Liebowitz takes a different stance to market inefficiencies through discussing dubious
behaviour demonstrated by market participants (2005:32). Such inefficient behaviour
discussed by Liebowitz include: “Process vs. Outcome” where losses are more meticulously
analysed as opposed to gains. The issue that arises due to the “Process vs. Outcome”
irrationality is that managers who neglect to analyse gains thoroughly never truly know if the
gains were generated through a sound investment process or due to other factors resulting in
‘dumb luck’ (2005:34). The “Convoy Behaviour” is described as the behavioural bias of
mainstream participants who follow other institutional managers’ portfolios for fear of
greater risk should they ‘sail solo’ (Liebowitz, 2005:35). Liebowitz states that in times of
market ambiguity, people are naturally inclined to follow their peers’ behaviour (2005:35).
4
Liebowitz expands on other key behavioural biases of market participants, all which result in
the same conclusion; that human behavioural biases create acute market inefficiencies which
are exploitable by ‘Pure Alpha’ funds and have been exploited consistently over many
decades (Liebowitz, 2005:32).
Finally, Doukas, Kim, and Pantzalis put forth the idea that arbitrageurs play an important role
in capital market efficiency (2010). This is no remarkable finding, but they go on to explain
that arbitrage contains implicit risk due to idiosyncratic factors affecting stocks (Doukas et al.
2010). Due to arbitrage risk, mispriced securities with high levels of idiosyncratic risk may
remain mispriced due to the failure of arbitrageurs to effectively manage the implied risk of
making the arbitrage trade. This results in the persistence of market inefficiency (Doukas et
al. 2010).
Is Active and Passive Management Mutually Exclusive?
There is a false dichotomy prevalent in the debate between ‘Actives’ versus ‘Passives’, where
proponents of either strategy vehemently denounce the legitimacy of the other on the grounds
of academic theory. It is safe to say, according to Markowitz’s MPT, that all rational and risk
averse investors want to maximise return for a given level of risk or minimise risk for a given
level of return: in other words, to invest in the optimal portfolio (1952).
Ambachtsheer, Farrell and Farrell say that active management adds value to a portfolio
through management’s ability to identify key requirements for generating alpha returns
(1979). Value-added or residual expected returns are dependent on (i) management skill and
their ability to make reasonable valuation judgements, (ii) the conversion of valuation
judgements into unbiased residual return expectations, (iii) portfolio construction rules that
consider transaction costs and risk controls, and (iv) the availability of software computation
for data processing (Ambachtsheer, Farrell and Jr, 1979:45).
Sorensen, Miller and Samak evaluate the value-added from active management on the
grounds of manager skill, where skill is calculated on the historic stock-picking success of a
manager measured as a percentage of their historical success versus failures (1998). It is
concluded that mutual and pension funds who employ managers, who consistently experience
index performance or worse, should replace them with managers who have a success rate of
56% or better (Sorensen et al, 1998). However, even if a fund can access superior managers,
5
optimisation of risk adjusted returns requires the use of passive instruments or quantitative
index-enhancing products (Sorensen et al. 1998).
Literature Evaluation and Working Hypothesis in a South African Context
Literature on active and passive investment strategies rely on key assumptions regarding the
degree to which markets are efficient. Proponents of passive strategies are so by default given
their belief of the EMH. Although strong-form efficiency is a stretch of the imagination,
proponents of the EMH find it reasonable to assume that developed markets satisfy
weak-form and semi-strong-form efficiency. Although the EMH allows for mispricing and
return anomalies to occur in the market, it states that these anomalies occur at random and
cannot prevail. Thus, it is logical to conclude that proponents of the EMH disregard the value
added from active managers.
Most of the literature on the subject finds issues with the EMH and the simplifying
assumptions behind pricing models, namely the CAPM. Attempts to support the EMH and
the CAPM, although theoretically sound and offers insights into the mechanics of the
theories, offer no practical value to industry practitioners. The literature finds that
inefficiencies do persist due to biased behaviour of market participants or structural barriers
which prevent the correct pricing of marketable assets, as discussed in Liebowitz’s (2005)
and Doukas et al (2011) articles respectively.
South Africa has an advanced financial sector coupled with a relatively small capital market.
Just as practitioners have and continue to generate pure alpha returns globally, it is believed
that industry practitioners have the means to exploit inefficiencies that potentially exist in
South Africa’s capital markets through active management strategies. This hypothesis can be
tested through comparing various active, passive, and hybrid fund performances situated in
South Africa.
Conclusion
This literature review explores the debate between active and passive investing. First, the
defence of efficient markets and thus passive investment strategies is considered with most of
the literature agreeing that markets are operationally efficient and that passive strategies are
greatly beneficial to investors. Second, the defence of active management considering market
inefficiency is explored. Proponents of active management identify the importance of index
funds and other quantitative index-enhancing products. However, active management relies
6
on the ability of superior managers to take advantage of acute market inefficiencies to
generate pure alpha returns. Industry practitioners and financial academics note the existence
of superior managers and largely agree that markets are mostly efficient allowing for active
management to better allocate capital, thus resulting in a more efficient market. Finally, the
false dichotomy of active versus passive investment is considered. It is noted that optimised
portfolios rely on passive and quantitative index-enhanced products in conjunction with
superior stock-selection skills of an active manager. Most of the literature reviewed agrees
that markets are operationally efficient, but acute inefficiencies do arise allowing for the
exploitation of such inefficiencies and thus the generation of excess returns. However, it is
important for active management to balance excess returns with marginal risk.
Methodology
Introduction
Given the literature reviewed, it was possible to design the research question and develop the
data-analysis strategy with sound academic practises. The following chapter describes the
research paradigm employed to analyse the observed data collected as well as the theoretical
underpinnings for the analysis of the data, all of which was informed by the reviewed
literature. The research design and data collection methods are discussed in depth, followed
by the reliability and validity of the approaches employed. Finally, the data-analysis strategy
and ethical considerations are discussed.
Paradigm
The research question considers whether it is relevant and appropriate for asset managers to
chase alpha at the risk of their client’s capital. This question requires a quantitative analysis
of returns data of various South African domiciled equity funds whilst adhering to
widely-held academic beliefs about asset pricing. The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
is primarily considered for securities pricing in this paper. The CAPM suggests that
individual securities are correctly priced given their beta risk or systematic risk in the
long-run. Additionally, equity funds are comprised of individual equity securities, thus
applying the CAPM to the analysis of these funds is deemed appropriate given the
time-period under consideration.
Due to the nature of the research methods required, it is fitting to use a post-positivist
paradigm for the quantitative analysis of the returns data observed. The research question
7
looks to uncover new information which can be applied to South African equity funds given
South African economic and market conditions. Additionally, Critical Realism will be
employed due to the changing nature of pricing-model theories in financial academia.
Examples of changing pricing models include; the adjustments made to the CAPM by
Michael Jensen (1967)
in explaining alpha returns, or the CAPM adjustments made by
Eugene Fama and Kenneth French (1996) in their Three-Factor Model which explains excess
returns by adding a size and value premium over and above the market risk premium
considered in Treynor (1962), Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin’s (1966) original
CAPM.
E (Ri ) = Rf + β (M RP )
Lintner, Mossin, Sharpe, and Treynor’s CAPM
(1)
E (Ri ) − Rf = αi + β (M RP )
Jensen’s Alpha
(2)
E (Ri ) = Rf + β 1 (M RP ) + β 2 (SM B) + β 3 (HM L)
Fama-French 3FM
(3)
Where:
E (Ri ) =
Expected return for asset i
Rf
=
Risk Free Rate (Yields on respective government bonds or treasury bills)
βi
=
Slope coefficient of asset returns regressed on respective benchmark returns
αi
=
Jensen’s alpha return over and above benchmark (can be negative)
M RP =
Market Risk Premium
SM B =
Size Premium (Small minus big)
HM L =
Value Premium (High minus low)
Final considerations made for the post-positivist paradigm employed include; the treatment of
Finance as a social science with respects to how people play an integral role in price
discovery, the objectivity of unchanging historical quantitative returns data, and the
observational nature of secondary data collection methods used.
Theoretical Framework
The theoretical underpinnings of active vs passive investing rely on the assumptions made
about market efficiency. The reviewed literature mostly concludes that markets are efficient
8
but that acute mispricing does occur due to several factors. Mispricing primarily occurs due
to human behaviour, as discussed by Liebowitz (2005), and due to the failure of closing out
arbitrage opportunities caused by implicit arbitrage risk and other financial implications, as
discussed by Doukas, Kim, and Pantzalis (2010).
These acute mispricings which occur at random, as per the EMH, provide the incentive
necessary for active managers to pursue excess returns. As summarised by Grossman and
Stiglitz, active management and security analysis must receive a premium in a world of
costly information, otherwise there would be no incentive to collect and analyse data (1980).
By looking at historical returns data over a long period of time and measuring the volatility of
these returns can one most accurately forecast trends in the future. As per Figlewski,
historical data bases assumptions on stability which are unlikely to hold over time (1994).
However, historical risk data over long periods of time generally provide the most accurate
forecasts for both long- and short-time horizons (Figlewski, 1994). Thus, the assumption of
current risk continuing into future time periods, given historical risk data, can be made with
little effect on the outcome of the research conducted. This assumption implies that superior
funds on a risk-adjusted basis will continue to be superior going into the future. Additionally,
superior funds can be identified ex ante b y considering past risk adjusted past performance,
macro-economic past performance, manager characteristics, and analyses of fund holdings
(Jones & Wermers, 2011).
Research Approach/Research Design
The research question was answered by comparing South African-domiciled equity funds
risk-adjusted returns against an appropriate broad-market benchmark’s returns. The chosen
benchmark was the JSE Ltd All Share Index (JSE ALSI) weighted by market capitalisation.
The index designation is J203 on The Bloomberg Terminal.
Returns data on a monthly-basis over an eight-year period formed the foundation upon which
the research was conducted. Risk-adjusted metrics of the observed returns data was compared
to the benchmark returns data. The risk-adjusted equity fund returns were primarily treated
for average management fees whilst ignoring the effects of taxation, additional service fees,
and transaction costs.
The key assumption made when comparing actively managed equity funds against the
passive equity fund is that the passive equity fund has zero tracking-error. That is, holders of
9
the passive equity fund essentially hold the J203. With the passive fund established, risk
adjustments and fee adjustments were made to the J203 to effectively compare both strategies
pari passu.
Mean risk-adjusted metrics of actively managed equity funds were tested against the
respective metric of the passive equity fund using the right tailed Student’s T-Test at the five
percent level of significance. The p-value approach was employed. Three groups of tests
were conducted on mean risk-adjusted metrics: 1) zero fees 2) lower-bound fees 3)
upper-bound fees.
Data Collection
The data collected was first sourced on a Thomson Reuters DataStream global financial and
macroeconomic data platform. The search was narrowed down to South African-domiciled,
Rand denominated equity funds. The funds’ price data was pulled from The Bloomberg
Terminal using a Bloomberg Excel plug-in. Funds that passed the criteria of eight-years’
worth of monthly price data were used for the study. The time period chosen was arbitrary as
to allow as many funds as possible to be included in the study whilst allowing enough
monthly data points to be considered, given the central limit theorem, to ensure statistical
significance.
The sample consisted of 43 equity funds with eight-years’ worth of monthly price data. The
sample was tested against the J203 over the same period. The price data was converted to
returns data using natural logarithms, assuming that returns are compounded continuously,
and that trading occurs continuously. Continuous trading was assumed given the continuous
passage of time.
The sample was drawn from the universe of South African-domiciled, Rand denominated
equity funds with an unknown population variance. Thus, a right-tailed Student’s T-Test was
employed at the five percent level of significance with 42 degrees of freedom.
Additionally, a sub-sample of 29 equity funds was tested against the passive J203 fund using
a right-tailed Student’s T-test with 28 degrees of freedom. This sample contains “superior”
equity funds with mean returns greater than or equal to the mean return of the J203. The
theoretical reasoning for the selection of this sample relies on Figlewski’s (1994) and Jones
and Wermers’ (2011) findings that 1) past historic risk data is a good measure for risk trends
in the future and, 2) that superior fund performance can be identified ex ante given past fund
10
and macroeconomic performance, respectively. The idea was to see how “superior” actively
managed equity funds stacked up to the J203 passive fund over the given time period on a
risk adjusted basis.
11
Validity and Reliability
The data was sourced from financial information services used as global industry staples.
Both Thomson Reuters DataStream and The Bloomberg Terminal are industry leading
financial information software-as-a-service providers. The data sources were utilised on the
University of Cape Town’s (UCT) campuses through UCT’s subscription of the services.
The statistical method employed for comparing sample means was appropriate. The Student’s
T-Test was used due to the unknown variance of the population from which the samples were
drawn.
The data treatment was in line with industry and academic standards of comparing and
ranking fund or security returns. The funds were compared on a risk-adjusted performance
basis through calculating widely used risk-adjusted metrics (Estrada, 2011:99-122):
-
Sharpe Ratio
-
Treynor Ratio
-
Information Ratio
-
Modigliani-Modigliani (M2) Risk-Adjusted Performance (RAP)
-
Semi-Standard Deviations (SSD)
The above metrics were adjusted for respective management fees.
Data Analysis Strategy
The returns data obtained through the method described in ‘Data Collection’ was used to
calculate an array of statistics used to determine the risk adjusted performance of each equity
fund compared to the J203 benchmark. The metrics calculated were:
-
Tracking error of the equity fund against the J203
-
Beta coefficient of the respective equity fund’s returns regressed on the J203’s
returns
-
Mean monthly returns of the equity funds and the J203, whilst ignoring geometric
mean returns as the study focuses on period-for-period performance and not the
evolution of investments over the period considered
-
Standard deviation of the equity funds’ and the J203’s returns
12
-
Semi-standard deviations of equity fund returns, or downside risk. That is, the
standard deviation of fund returns below the mean return of the J203
-
Risk free rate, calculated as the mean yield on the R186 South African Sovereign
domestic currency 10-year bond over the period under review
-
CAPM expected return for each fund using the theoretical underpinning of the
CAPM theory and calculated with the risk-free rate, beta coefficient and the
market risk premium
The above statistics were used in the calculation of the risk-adjusted metrics discussed in
‘Validity and Reliability’ above.
Finally, the risk adjusted metrics were treated for three fee scenarios; 0%, 1.75%, and 2.5%
for the actively managed equity funds whilst the J203 passively managed fund was also
adjusted for three fee scenarios; 0%, 0.03%, and 0.04%.
The fees applied to the risk-adjusted metrics of the equity funds were informed by the
average active management fees in South Africa (Sygnia, 2016). The fees paid on the passive
J203 was informed by management fees paid for Satrix’s JSE ALSI ETF (Satrix, 2018).
Ethical Considerations
Under no circumstances were the resources provided by UCT used for individual financial
gain by the researcher nor will the resources provided by UCT be used for individual
financial gain by the researcher.
The findings of the research paper are academic in nature and are intended to inform readers
on the topic at hand and are in no way meant to act as trading or investing advice.
Conclusion
The methods used in conducting the analysis of data was discussed in depth. The
methodology employed has allowed a statistical analysis of the observed data to be
performed with some degree of statistical significance. The next chapter reviews the results
of the data-analysis and further discusses the outcome of the data-analysis performed.
13
Results and Discussion
Introduction
The previous chapter laid down the methods used to acquire the results needed to make
statistical inferences. The results acquired were used to test whether actively managed equity
funds outperformed passively managed equity funds on a risk adjusted basis at the five
percent level of significance using a right-tailed Student’s T-test. This chapter presents the
results obtained through the methodology discussed above. First, the descriptive statistics are
presented and discussed, followed by statistical inferences comparing both management
strategies which is then discussed. Finally, concluding remarks on the results are presented.
Descriptive Statistics
The descriptive statistics presented in table 1 compare the three component measures of
central tendency required for the risk adjusted metrics discussed in “Validity and Reliability”
in the Methodology section above. The measures of central tendency used are: the sample
mean, the sample standard deviation, and the sample semi-standard deviation. Where
semi-standard deviations measure downside risk below a given benchmark. The benchmark
considered in this study was the JSE ALSI Index (J203). Additionally, the descriptive
statistics compares the sample of actively managed equity funds, the sub-sample of superior
actively managed equity funds, and the passive J203 equity fund, all before fee adjustments.
Table 1 describes mean monthly measures of central tendency.
Metric
Mean Mean-Returns
Mean Standard Deviation
Mean Semi-Standard Deviation
Equity Funds
0.7719%
2.8684%
1.9097%
Superior Equity Funds (ex-post)
0.8880%
3.1199%
1.9072%
J-%
2.9301%
2.9301%
Table 1: Mean monthly measures of central tendency
On average, the sample of actively managed equity funds offer greater returns and less
variability and less downside variability than the J203 before fees. This result falls in line
with Jones & Wermers’ results where it is noted that the average active manager performs
slightly worse than the market index by an amount just less than their fees (2011). This
suggests that the average active fund creates alpha returns before fees and expenses (Jones &
Wermers, 2011). The average ex-post superior fund offers an even greater return over the
J203 but with marginally more variability in the returns. However, downside variability of
the average superior fund returns is substantially lower than the downside variability of the
14
J203. The lower downside variability of the average superior fund compared to the J203 is
not surprising given the performance disparity between the average superior fund and the
J203.
Risk-Adjusted Performance before Fees
Ranking the performance of various securities by returns alone gives no helpful insight as to
how effectively the securities in question meet investment objectives. Risk needs to be spent
adequately to meet investment goals and is extremely important when making investment
decisions. Knowing the variability of historic returns can adequately shed light on the future
variability of returns (Figlewski, 1996). Table 3 c ompares various mean risk-adjusted
measures between the average active equity fund, the average superior fund, and the passive
J203.
etric
M
Mean Sharpe Ratio
Mean Treynor Ratio
Mean Information Ratio
Mean M2
Mean M2 (SSD)
Equity Funds-%
0.7180%
Superior Equity Funds (ex-post-%
1.0301%
Table 2: Mean monthly risk-adjusted metrics before fees.
J-%
0.7117%
The first interesting result is the greater Sharpe ratio of the J203 over the average equity
fund’s Sharpe ratio. Table 1 shows that the average active equity fund offers a greater return
for less variability. However, table 2 shows that the passive J203 is a more efficient portfolio
than the average active equity fund. The mean Sharpe ratio value in table 2 is the average of
all Sharpe ratios across the sample of actively managed equity funds. The conflicting results
between table 1 and table 2 are attributable to many active funds exhibiting lower Sharpe
ratios than the J203’s Sharpe ratio, or negative Sharpe ratios. A negative Sharpe ratio occurs
when the expected CAPM return of the security is less than the risk-free rate.
The average information ratio of active equity funds is positive. This suggests that the
average actively managed equity fund is creating alpha returns above the respective J203
benchmark before fees. This finding falls in line with both Jones and Wermers’ (2011) and
Grossman and Stiglitz’s (1980) arguments; where it is postulated that the average fund
manager produces alpha returns before fees, and that in a world of costly information,
analysts must receive a premium for their work or else there would be no incentive for these
analysts to collect and analyse data, respectively.
15
Table 3 below summarises the statistical inferences made on various metrics of the average
active fund compared to the J203, given zero fees. The null hypothesis states that the average
active fund metric is equal to the respective J203 metric. The alternative hypothesis states
that the average active fund metric is greater than the respective J203 metric. Statistical
inferences were made at the five percent level of significance using the right-tailed Student’s
T-test given the unknown population variation in returns of South African domiciled, Rand
denominated, actively managed equity funds. The t-tests were conducted with 43
observations and 42 degrees of freedom.
Zero Fees One Tailed: CV = 1.682
Metric
Sharpe Ratio
Treynor Ratio
Information Ratio
RAP (SD)
RAP (SSD)
Test Statistic
-7.4843
-
-
P-Value-
Decision
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
Reject Null Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
Reject Null Hypothesis
Table 3: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, zero fees. Average active fund vs J203.
The average equity fund’s Sharpe ratio, Treynor ratio, and M2 risk adjusted performance
(RAP), using standard deviations, is not greater than the J203’s respective ratios. This is
largely attributable to many active funds exhibiting low or negative Sharpe and Treynor
ratios which leads to a low M2 RAP. Low or negative Sharpe and Treynor ratios occur when
the CAPM expected return of an active fund is close to or less than the expected return on the
J203, respectively. The M2 RAP is largely dependent on a security’s Sharpe ratio. However,
the average active fund exhibits a positive information ratio, where the market portfolio
would theoretically have an information ratio of zero.
Finally, given zero fees, the M2 RAP
using downside risk or semi-standard deviations is greater the
M2 RAP of the J203. The J203’s semi-standard deviation (SSD) is equal to its standard deviation
because the J203 is the benchmark; where SSD measure variation of returns below the average
benchmark return.
The rejection of the null hypothesis with respects to the average active fund’s information ratio and
M2 RAP, using SSD, suggests that the average active fund does produce excess returns before fees, as
per Grossman & Stiglitz (1980) and Wermers & Jones (2011).
Table 4 below summarises the statistical inferences made on various metrics of the average
superior active fund compared to the J203, given zero fees. The null and alternative
hypotheses remain the same as above and are also conducted at the five percent level of
16
significance using the right tailed Student’s T-test. The t-tests were conducted with 29
observations and 28 degrees of freedom.
Metric
Sharpe Ratio
Treynor Ratio
Information Ratio
RAP (SD)
RAP (SSD)
Zero Fees One Tailed: CV = 1.701
Test Statistic
P-Value-
Decision
Reject Null Hypothesis
Reject Null Hypothesis
Reject Null Hypothesis
Reject Null Hypothesis
Reject Null Hypothesis
Table 4: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, zero fees. Average superior (ex-post) active
fund vs J203.
The average superior fund has greater risk adjusted performance metrics, on all considered
fronts, than the J203, before fees. If superior funds can be identified ex-ante a s per
Figlewski’s (1996) long term risk-analysis and Jones & Wermers’ (2011) analysis of historic
fund performance, then allocation of capital to superior funds could offer excess returns over
the J203 with lower downside variability in returns before fees.
Risk-Adjusted Performance after Fees
The fee structures employed for actively managed funds were informed by Sygnia’s (2016)
article, “Are You Getting Value for Your Investment Fees?”, featured on Moneyweb.co.za.
The fees employed for the J203 were informed by Satrix’s JSE ALSI (J203) exchange traded
fund fact sheet. The average active fund and the average superior active fund was tested
against the J203 on three fee-scenarios; zero fees (see above), lower-bound fees, and
upper-bound fees. Table 5 and Table 6 below summarise the statistical inferences made on
comparing various risk-adjusted metrics between active funds and the passive J203 fund after
lower-bound fees. The null and alternative hypotheses remain the same from above.
Metric
Sharpe Ratio
Treynor Ratio
Information Ratio
RAP (SD)
RAP (SSD)
Lower-Bound Fees One Tailed: CV = 1.682
Test Statistic
P-Value
Decision
-
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
-
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
-
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
-
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
-
Do Not Reject Null Hypothesis
Table 5: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, lower-bound Fees. Average active fund vs
J203
17
Metric
Sharpe Ratio
Treynor Ratio
Information Ratio
RAP (SD)
RAP (SSD)
Lower-Bound Fees One Tailed: CV = 1.701
Test Statistic
P-Value
Decision-
Reject Null Hypothesis-
Reject Null Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null-
Hypothesis-
Reject Null Hypothesis-
Reject Null Hypothesis
Table 6: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, lower-bound fees. Average superior
(ex-post) active fund vs J203
After lower-bound fees, it is apparent that the average actively managed fund falls short of
the market-index on all considered risk-adjusted fronts. This finding falls in line with most of
the literature on the subject. Keane’s (1986) and Liebowitz’s (2005) findings considers fees
from chasing an active management approach and conclude that passive strategies make more
sense given no guarantee of outperforming the market. Additionally, Jones & Wermers’
(2011) find that the average active equity fund underperforms the broad-market index after
fees. However, it is implied that the average passive fund also underperforms the index after
fees; that is, if passive funds are meant to have zero-tracking error, any application of fees
will reduce returns (Jones & Wermers, 2011). Jones & Wermers state, “In fact, virtually 100
percent of passive funds underperform their relevant indices, net of fees” (2011:31).
Average ex-post superior active funds tell a more promising story after lower-bound fees as
they outperform the J203 on all considered risk-adjusted metrics barring the information
ratio. The failure to reject the null hypothesis at the five percent level of significance when
considering the information ratio of the superior active fund compared to the J203 can be
attributed to the variation of returns of the average ex-post s uperior fund, as seen above in the
Descriptive Statistics s ection. The information ratio’s denominator is the standard deviation
of the differences between a security’s returns and its respective benchmark. The higher
variation in returns of the average superior fund compared to the variation in returns of the
J203 could imply a larger standard deviation of the differences in returns, thus inflating the
denominator of the information ratio, and thus lowering the ratio.
Table 7 and table 8 b elow summarise the statistical inferences made on comparing various
risk-adjusted metrics between active funds and the passive J203 fund after higher-bound fees.
The null and alternative hypotheses remain the same from above.
18
Metric
Sharpe Ratio
Treynor Ratio
Information Ratio
RAP (SD)
RAP (SSD)
Higher-Bound Fees One Tailed: CV = 1.682
Test Statistic
P-Value
Decision
Do Not Reject Null
-
Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null
-
Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null
-
Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null
-
Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null
-
Hypothesis
Table 7: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, higher-bound fees. Average active fund vs
J203.
Metric
Sharpe Ratio
Treynor Ratio
Information Ratio
RAP (SD)
RAP (SSD)
High Fees One Tailed: CV = 1.701
Test Statistic
P-Value
Decision
Do Not Reject Null-
Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null-
Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null
-
Hypothesis
Do Not Reject Null-
Hypothesis-
Reject Null Hypothesis
Table 8: Right tailed Student’s T-test statistical inference summary, higher-bound fees. Average superior
(ex-post) active fund vs J203.
The average actively managed equity fund fails to reject the null hypothesis on all
risk-adjusted fronts given higher-bound fees. This is no surprise given that the average
actively managed equity fund failed to reject the null hypothesis on all risk-adjusted fronts for
lower-bound fees.
The average ex-post s uperior actively managed fund fails to reject the null hypothesis on all
risk-adjusted fronts barring the M2 RAP metric adjusted for downside variations in returns. It
was found that downside variations in returns of the superior fund was lower than that of the
J203 which explains the greater adjusted RAP of the superior fund over the J203.
Implications of Findings
Not surprisingly, given the level of development of South Africa’s financial sector, the
findings closely match what has been uncovered in developed financial markets, as discussed
by the consulted literature. However, the study does not disregard active management
completely. Valuable information regarding the method of selecting superior active funds has
19
surfaced when considering Figlewski’s (1996) analysis of historic return variations and Jones
& Wermers’ (2011) methods for identifying superior active managers.
If superior actively managed funds can be selected using historic risk-analyses and historic
performance metrics of funds and fund managers, then alpha should be generated on a
recurring basis. However, the capturing of recurring alpha returns relies on an active
management of funds, that is, actively managing one’s portfolio of active funds, ignoring
transaction costs and taxes. Given the apparent failure of the average actively managed fund
compared to the J203 benchmark, it is not advisable to hold a passive instrument which tracks
active funds, such as a fund tracker ETF or index-styled investment vehicles tracking active
funds.
Concluding Remarks
The research question explores the propriety and relevance of chasing excess returns in South
African context. A South African context was considered given how small South Africa’s
capital market is relative to other large developed capital markets abroad. The literature
largely agreed that markets are efficient at disseminating information quickly and at almost
no cost. However, the efficient market hypothesis does not explain acute mispricings in
capital markets, which opens discussions as to how effectively can active managers exploit
inefficiencies at the risk of their clients’ capital.
The methodology employed tested mean monthly risk-adjusted metrics against their
respective benchmark (J203) risk-adjusted metrics at the five percent level of significance
using the right-tailed Student’s T-test. The average active fund outperformed the J203 before
fees but failed when risk-adjusted metrics were adjusted for fees. However, the average
superior active fund outperformed the J203 before and after fees on risk-adjusted
performance.
These findings suggest that excess returns can be generated consistently given the appropriate
due diligence required to identify superior funds ex-ante. The research further suggests that
financial instruments which track active funds will not outperform its respective benchmark
and that an active management approach to managing a pool of active funds is required to
generate excess returns, ignoring taxes and transaction costs.
20
Limitations and Recommendations
The primary research limitation is the failure of avoiding survivorship bias effectively. Many
funds ceased to exist for the entire period under review. Survivorship bias was deemed
acceptable to ignore as it was of the view that the impact of the exclusion of funds would not
detract from the general message of the research conducted.
Additionally, many new funds opened within the period under review. Unfortunately, fund
closures and openings were excluded from the sample selected. The best way to counter this
issue is to test the performance of each fund for the period in which it was open against its
respective benchmark over the same period. The unavoidable problem faced is the amount
investors lost on the Rand when funds were liquidated. Without this knowledge, it is futile to
make any statistical inference on the performance of these funds under the period reviewed.
Another limitation worth disclosing is the assumptions upon which asset pricing models are
made. It was assumed that markets are ‘mostly’ efficient, given the literature reviewed, and
that the CAPM does hold on average over the long-run. However, though it is a theory widely
used in industry, its shortcomings do pose questions as to whether expected returns based on
the CAPM are appropriate to use when conducting risk-adjusted returns calculations.
It is recommended that future researchers decide upon which assumptions are appropriate
when considering which pricing models to use when calculating risk-adjusted metrics. The
CAPM has many adjustments, as discussed in the literature review and in the methodology.
A final recommendation on survivorship bias is the identifying of liquidation costs to
investors upon fund closures. However, this data may be largely absent and costly to obtain.
It is recommended that an average cost to investors is determined between bounds and that a
statistical inference be made on various levels between the bounds set by the researchers.
21
References
Ambachtsheer, K. P., Farrell, J. L. & Farrell, J. J. L., 1979. Can Active Management Add
Value?. Financial Analysts Journal, 35(6), pp. 39-47.
Banz, R. W., 1981. The Relationship between Return and Market Value of Common Stocks.
Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 9, pp. 3-18.
Delcey, T., 2018. Efficient Market Hypothesis, Eugene Fama and Paul: A reevaluatin.
[Online]
Available at: https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-v2
[Accessed 8 August 2018].
Doukas, J. A., Kim, C. & Pantzalis, C., 2010. Arbitrage Risk and Stock Mispricing. The
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(4), pp. 907-934.
Estrada, J., 2011. The Financial Times Guide To Understanding Finance, A No-Nonsense
Companion To Financial Tools and Techniques. 2nd ed. Harlow: Prentice Hall Financial
Times.
Eun, C. S., 1994. The Benchmark Beta, CAPM, and Pricing Anomalies. Oxford Economic
Papers, 46(2), pp. 330-343.
Fama, E. &. F. K., 1996. Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies. [ Online]
Available at: https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/j-.tb05202.x
[Accessed 7 November 2018].
Fama, E. F., 1969. Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work. The
Journal of Finance, 25(2), pp. 383-417.
Figlewski, S., 1996. Forecasting Volatility Using Historical Data. The Journal of Finance, L
I,
NO. 1(March), pp. 1-29.
Friend, I. & Blume, M., 1970. Measurement of Portfolio Performance Under Uncertainty.
The American Economic Review, 60(4), pp. 561-575.
Grinold, R. C. & Kahn, R. N., 2000. Active Portfolio Management: A Quantitative Approach
for Providing Superior Returns and Controlling Risk. 2nd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Grossman, S. J. & Stiglitz, J. E., 1980. On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient
Markets. The American Economic Review, 7 0(3), pp. 393-408.
Jones, R. C. & Wermers, R., 2011. Active Management in Mostly Efficient Markets.
Financial Analysts Journal, 67(6), pp. 29-45.
Keane, S. M., 1986. The Efficient Market Hypothesis on Trial. Financial Analysts Journal,
42(2), pp. 58-63.
Liebowitz, M. L., 2005. Alpha Hunters and Beta Grazers. Financial Analysts Journal, 6 1(5),
pp. 32-39.
7
Markowitz, H., 1952. Portfolio Selection. The Journal of Finance, 7(1), pp. 77-91.
Reinganum, M. R., 1981. A New Empirical Perspective on the CAPM. The Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 1 6(4), pp. 439-462.
Roll, R., 1977. A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory's Test. Part I: On Past and Potential
Testability of the Theory.. Journal of Financial Economics, Volume 4, pp. 129-176.
Satrix, 2018. Minimum Disclosure Document (Fund Fact Sheet) Satrix ALSI Index Fund.
[Online]
Available at: https://satrix.co.za/media/26891?inline=true
[Accessed 10 November 2018].
Sharpe, W. F., 1964. Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions
of Risk. The Journal of Finance, 19(3), pp. 425-442.
Sorensen, E. H., Miller, K. L. & Samak , V., 1998. Allocating between Active and Passive
Management. Financial Analysts Journal, 5 4(5), pp. 18-31.
Sygnia, 2016. Are You Getting Value for Your Investment Fees? Step One: Know what
you're paying. Step two: find out if it's worth paying for.. [Online]
Available at:
https://www.moneyweb.co.za/investing/unit-trusts/are-you-getting-value-for-your-investment
-fees/
[Accessed 10 November 2018].
Vasicek, O. A. & McQuown, J. A., 1972. The Efficient Market Model. Financial Analyst
Journal, 28(5), pp. 71-84.
8