Independent
Researcher
PRICE CONTROLS
Social Benefit or Social Cost?
Published by Bridgestone Associates
Date: January 14th, 2020
The use of price controls by governments is common across
markets and economies. While sometimes used as a tool for
social dogma, price controls can throw cold water on
investment and growth, deteriorate poverty outcomes, cause
heavy fiscal burdens on countries, and jeopardize the
effectiveness of monetary policy.
Better socioeconomic nets along with market competition and
a sound regulatory environment, can be both pro-poor and
pro-growth. However, such developments need to be carefully
communicated and sequenced to ensure political and social
acceptance. Where price control exist, it should be transparent
and sponsor by well-capitalized stabilization funds or national
hedging strategies to ensure fiscal sustainability.
Independent
Researcher
Governments have been trying to set maximum
or minimum prices since ancient times. If we
look at the history, we see a lot of situations
where policy makers influenced the markets
through price controls.
Although application of price controls is
understandable, as it holds out the promise of
protecting groups that are particularly hardpressed to meet price increases, they fail to
protect many consumers and hurt others. One
of the reason for this is that Price Controls
tends to create Price Distortions.
Price distortions are defined as instances “when
prices and production are higher or lower than the
level that would usually exist in a competitive
market”.
Price controls can be imposed in a variety of
ways. They may involve price ceilings, or price
floors, imposed on selected goods and services
by the authorities.
In emerging market and developing economies,
price controls on goods are often imposed to
serve socio-economic objectives. They may be
part of government efforts to protect
vulnerable consumers, by addressing market
failures or subsidizing the cost of essential
goods. Or they may be intended to maintain the
incomes of producers, as part of a pricesupport program. Alternatively, they can serve
the purpose of price smoothing, especially for
key commodities subject to high volatility in
international markets. This can lower
uncertainty about households’ real incomes and
firms’ production costs.
Nonetheless, Price Controls tends to force
challenges to growth and development in the
economy.
UNDERSTANDING PRICE FLOOR & PRICE
CEILING
Price Ceiling means firms are not allowed to set
prices above a certain level. The aim is to reduce
prices below the market equilibrium price.
Whereas Price Floor is the minimum price that
producers are allowed to charge. They are usually
set above the market equilibrium.
Both, Price Ceiling and Price Floor tends to effect
the supply and demand of the products and
services. When prices are established by a free
market, then there is a balance between supply and
demand. However, when the government imposes
price controls, then there will be either excess
supply or excess demand.
A price ceiling creates a shortage when the legal
price is below the market equilibrium price, but
has no effect on the quantity supplied if the legal
price is above the market equilibrium price. A
price ceiling below the market equilibrium price
creates a shortage that causes consumers to
compete vigorously for the limited supply. Supply
is limited because suppliers are not getting the
prices that would allow them to earn a profit.
Likewise, price floor creates excess supply if the
legal price is above the market price. Suppliers are
willing to supply more at the price floor than the
market wants at that price.
CHALLENGES OF PRICE CONTROL
As discussed previously, intentions behind price
controls is to improve social outcomes, however it
often hinders growth and development prospects,
impose fiscal burdens and can weaken the
usefulness of monetary policy.
Growth challenges. The use of price controls
can have adverse consequences for growth for
several reasons:
• Stifled competition and reduced investment.
Price ceilings can depress producer margins
and discourage domestic investment and
entrepreneurial activity. If margins depend on
Independent
Researcher
subsidies to local businesses to compensate
for price controls, they can discourage
foreign investment in those sectors by
increasing the country risk premium. In the
opposite case, where the controlled price is
above that required for a competitive return
to investment, its maintenance requires
barriers to entry or costly government
stockpiling of excess supply. Price-support
controls can depress competition and sustain
high producer margins.
• Distorted financial markets. Price controls in
the financial sector, such as ceilings on interest
rates can distort financial markets. These
measures reduce the supply of credit to safer
borrowers and small and medium-sized
enterprises, increase the level of nonperforming loans, reduce competition and
innovation in lending markets, and increase
informal lending. Moreover, they can
exacerbate inequality by limiting the poor’s
access to lending.
• Lower productivity. Price control regimes
may tilt the allocation of resources towards
the subsidized sector. Yet, such policies can
end up reducing productivity, and worsening
income inequality. They may lead to
inefficient use of subsidized inputs. They can
also adversely affect incentives to adopt
productivity-raising
new
technologies.
Empirical evidence suggests that marketoriented structural reforms, including the
reduction of price controls and their related
subsidies, are strongly associated with
improved firm-level productivity. Conversely,
in the case of petroleum products, high
subsidies that underpin price controls appear
to be associated with lower per capita output
growth.
• Increased vulnerability to climate change. Price
controls and subsidies on energy products may
heighten vulnerability to climate change and
inhibit the transition to a climate-resilient, lowcarbon economy.
• Increased informality. Price controls that
distort
consumption
towards
pricecontrolled goods, can cause chronic
shortages of these goods, the formation of
parallel markets with higher prices, and
substitution
towards
lower-quality
alternatives. Similarly, producers of pricecontrolled goods may turn to black markets
which have elevated transaction costs and
lack basic regulation. In addition, the
situation encourages production to shift to
firms in the informal sector, which avoid
regulation.
Socioeconomic Challenges. The use of price
controls combined with large subsidies is an
inefficient tool for redistributing domestic income.
These policies tend to be inequitable, as wealthier
segments of the population, usually urban
consumers, benefit disproportionately given their
greater consumption of the price-controlled good
compared to rural consumers and producers. For
example, subsidies and below-market prices for
gasoline and liquid natural gas have proven highly
regressive, with only a small share of the subsidy
benefiting the poorest segments of the
population.
Fiscal challenges. Price controls impose an
explicit or implicit set of taxes and subsidies that
varies over time, and their enforcement may
require additional regulations to constrain
consumption and production. Typically, a system
of price controls on goods ends up as a growing
burden on either the fiscal budget and public debt
or the profitability of producers. Subsidies for
products subject to price controls, such as
petroleum, can be a large portion of government
expenditures, in some cases exceeding 10 percent
of GDP.
Independent
Researcher
Monetary policy challenges. Monetary policy
has played a major role in reducing inflation to a
low, stable rate, often in the context of an
explicit inflation-targeting regime. The key has
been a transparent strategy aimed at the
medium and longer term. This has largely
stabilized longer run expectations of inflation,
in line with central bank objectives. In these
circumstances, the one-off impact on the
inflation rate of the removal of price controls
can be handled with the help of careful
communication from policymakers as to the
strategy they will employ to get inflation back
on track. In LICs, however, the monetary policy
challenges go deeper. First, the wider use of
price controls complicates the choice of
inflation target by weakening the usefulness of
the overall CPI as a measure of underlying
inflation pressures. Second, it can raise inflation
because the authorities tend to respond
asymmetrically when faced with cost increases,
as is often the case in response to food price
shocks. Third, it can increase the stickiness of
the inflation process as changes in controlled
prices often involve a lengthy regulatory
process. Fourth, one-off changes in controlled
prices can have persistent effects on inflation in
LICs, where inflation expectations are less well
anchored. Lastly, price controls in the financial
sector, including ceilings on interest rates can
reduce the ability of monetary policy to affect
financial conditions.
Collateral damage from foreign price
controls.
LICs are also more vulnerable to the collateral
damage from other countries’ price controls on
food and energy, because of the high share of
food and energy in their consumption baskets
and trade. Policies by individual countries to
contain the effects of spikes in global
commodity process in their local markets have
been shown to have had the perverse effect of
raising global prices. Export restrictions in
major commodity producers exacerbate global
shortages, thus contributing to higher prices on
the international market.
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Price controls have been used to mitigate the
impact of commodity price volatility on the most
vulnerable members of society. However, most
governments have had difficulty designing
frameworks that deliver lasting benefits. Over
time, price stabilization policies often result in
costly and distortionary subsidies, posing
important challenges to growth, development,
and macroeconomic policy suggesting that other
policy instruments may be more effective in
achieving social protection objectives.
Comprehensive reforms of price control
policies and related subsidies. Replacing price
controls with expanded and better-targeted
social safety nets, coupled with structural
reforms, can be both pro-poor and pro-growth.
Indeed, policies to lower subsidies that underpin
price controls appear to be associated with
higher per capita output growth, in part because
savings generated by lower subsidies can fund
productivity-enhancing
education
and
infrastructure. The removal of price controls
needs to be coupled with targeted support for
those segments of the population that might be
adversely affected. The different prongs of
reforms, however, need to be carefully sequenced
and communicated.
Enhanced competition. Improving the competitive environment can be a more effective means
of lowering costs to consumers and producers
than the use of price controls. Carefully designed
and properly enforced antitrust laws and
consumer protection legislation, are essential
components of institutional frameworks that
support market mechanisms. A sound legal and
regulatory framework favoring competitive
markets provides a more effective response to
many of the problems that price controls
attempt to address. Even in the case where
incumbent firms maintained outsized market
shares, the presence of competition, and the
potential for new entrants, significantly lower
their markups.
Independent
Researcher
Disclaimer: The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect the official policy or position of any agency of the Pakistan government. Examples
of analysis performed within this article are only examples. They should not be utilized in real-world
analytic products as they are based only on very limited and dated open source information.
Assumptions made within the analysis are not reflective of the position of any Pakistan government
entity.
Contact Us:
Address: House 04, Street 39, Sector G-6/2, Islamabad. -.- www.bridgestoneassociates.com